Human Error Series – How to Exploit Biases and Defend Against Manipulation
This series was suggested by a member of /r/socialengineering, and upon reading his request it struck me that though many resources detail methods of manipulation that exploit these biases in one way or another, no author has aimed to explain how to exploit each individually and shown how to defend oneself against these biases. Further, we’re expected to be aware of which of the many biases are taking place and are being exploited at any given time, which requires a more detailed knowledge of the fundamental nature of these biases.
By explaining these biases and analyzing their place in hypothetical situations and how they could be abused, seen from the perspective of a social engineer, I hope to
Teach you a more fundamental understanding of human behavior and cognition.
Inspire you to use your own creativity and imagination to approach the subject of applied social psychology.
Allow you to see situations in a different light and be more adaptable in dealing with them.
Raise awareness and shed light on what is happening in your own mind when these biases are being turned against you by others.
Sociality and social interaction is an interplay of all manner of manipulations and influences, and what is apparent is not often what is actual. What you think is happening might not be as it seems, and might actually be a part of the game other people, and even your own brain, are playing with your mind.
Enjoy!
– Joven
The Ambiguity Effect
The What
The ambiguity effect is a bias where decision making is affected by a lack of information, or ambiguity. However, since multiple biases are affected by certain types of ambiguity and uncertainty, we use the nomer ambiguity effect specifically for the cognitive bias in decision making which effects our innate preference for choices where the probability of a favorable outcome is known versus those where the probability of a favorable outcome is unknown.
Key Takeaway: When given an option people are more likely to avoid the options in which the probability feels unknown.
A very rudimentary example would be the following hypothetical scenario:
I offer you the choice between two boxes of marbles, one of which has 50 red marbles and 50 black marbles, the other has a randomly chosen content of between 0-100 black marbles, and the rest (up until 100) being red marbles. Whichever box you choose, you choose a color and then take out one marble at random. If you predicted the correct color, you get $100.
Now, these two options are statistically no different. Either way you choose, you have the exact same chance of being correct and getting your $100. However, like everyone else, you will choose the first box, simply because you know the contents of that box. Even if I were to raise the winning amount to $120 for the second box, or $200, you would still choose the first box, as would I. Why? Because you have no idea what the exact chance is that you will win $200, but you do know the exact chance you will win $100.
Key Takeaway: People have a fundamental aversion towards uncertainty.
Investment works much the same for many people. Last year, investing in Dogecoin would’ve netted you over a 1000% return on your investment, and it was predicted to rise in around that margin. However, it was also considered a volatile commodity, and chances were you could stand to lose much of your investment. Even if given a similar option now, this would probably have dissuaded you from even considering it a possibility.
The Why:
Why is this effect harmful to you, and why could it be useful in social situations? Three reasons:
1. As game theory tells us, what matters most in decision making when taking into account these biases is ‘subjective probability,’ or how likely do you (or in social situations, your [[Wiki]Target]) think these probabilities are. The extent of likelihood will decide whether or not you will believe a certain course of action is the right course of action, and how fervently you believe it.
2. The chance of a certain situation or claim cannot only be magnified or minimized, but also deliberately obfuscated, meaning that a person can be dissuaded from making a certain choice by posing it as leading to an ambiguous outcome, or conversely, persuaded to make a certain choice by deliberately obfuscating the alternative, even when the other choice can also be viewed as ambiguous.
3. The opposite can also be done, where you call into question the likelihood of a situation either by making it unclear what that probability is when one has already been assigned, or raising the possibility that there is a chance of failure and so calling their certainty into question. As stated before, people have a fundamental aversion for uncertainty, and that is precisely why obfuscating an issue tends to make people want to leave that issue entirely.
Abusing the ambiguity effect to cast doubt on situations and influencing decisions falls under the more general tactic of Probability Abuse.
The How
In our first situation, let’s assume that we are running a pretext of Party Psychic in an attempt to woo a special lady. Now, we may have ascertained some information about her beforehand (through various means), and during our ‘reading’ we suddenly touch on an accident that she had when she was eleven years old. Upon detailing the intricacies of this event, where we ‘feel her continued distress and pain’ which we ‘sensed the moment she got in the room,’ the pesky skeptics in the room are asking out loud how we could possibly know such a thing, in an attempt not so much to thwart our reading as to plea for their cognitive dissonance to be resolved.
So, “how did you know that?”
At this point, it is clear that just saying “my inner spirit showed me” on its own is not going to help convince anyone of the veracity of your divine nature. So instead, we place it in a juxtaposition with a claim that, though more statistically likely in a realistic sense, feels incredibly implausible, much more then the simple suspension of disbelief that is required for our answer, “‘I just have a gift” or, in a grander show of self-aggrandizement, “it’s not mind reading, just basic deduction. There is an entire science behind it, and it is really quite easy once you get the hang of it.”
Then, the juxtaposition would be: “Well, either that, or I broke into her doctor’s office and checked her medical records, and though that would be quite easy to do for someone like me, I’d say it’s an awful lot of effort to put into twenty minutes’ worth of entertainment.”
(A similar and brilliant juxtaposition was famously used when Mentalist Derren Brown “predicted” the lottery numbers live on British television.)
So, this first uses the juxtaposition to create a false dichotomy between burglary and psychology, and then uses obfuscation to make the chance of the logical second situation more ambiguous then the first, thus making a person more willing to choose to believe your original explanation. The ‘favorable situation’ in this sense is the clarity and removal of doubt as to the explanation.
In our second situation, we’ll see why the ambiguity principle is more generally applicable, in the sense that it’s used to cast doubt on the alternative implicitly, rather than something you’d build an attack or interaction on.
Imagine you would want to get into a certain office but you have no access, as you’re not an employee. You have a fake business-ID on hand, though no real ID, and you have a matching outfit and a reason to be there. The moment you walk up to the security agent outside, and you make your introduction, he will first actively believe you at your word, and only then will his brain start finding reasons to reject your claim (as per the Rejection Principle).
It will do so based on various counterclaims that might enter his head, most importantly the immediate opposite claim “This guy is not who he says he is.” His favorable outcomes are the following:
You enter, he has done his job and will have you bother him no longer, you can do your job which means the boss will happy.
He catches you in a lie, he has caught an intruder, and he will get commended.
Of course, in general, these situations rely more on the fact that you make the second situation far less likely (and indeed, both ambiguity and probability reappraisal are in play), but in a strictly probability-base scenario he would then potentially still consider it further because it has an established chance that allows him to weigh the pro and cons of either decision. So, what you’re further doing is obfuscating the probability that some good, no matter how good, can come of doubt:
“What good will it do to run all the way back home and grab my ID? I have three more offices to visit today and I really don’t want to lose my job over this. Also, I have my business ID right here, name and everything. Surely that’ll do?”
The probability of him benefitting from pressing the issue is now completely unknown, he has been filled with fear of “the boss” that will take precedence over reassessing that probability, and he can’t stand there for five minutes considering his options. What is the easier, more certain decision at this point?
This point is perhaps more obvious when using this same tactic to trap someone else.
Suppose you wanted to bring someone under suspicion, in the above example of being an impersonator or, in a more relatable situation, cast doubt on a liar in your own social circles.
You could tell that same guard: “The worst thing that could happen if we call to check is a few minutes’ hold-up. If we don’t check, what are the odds he’s bad, and who knows what could happen?”
There is still the probability of loss in the sense that the guy could be genuine and then genuinely annoyed and angry, but now the alternative is reframed to be obscure instead. “Who knows what could happen?” and “what are the odds?” imply a heavy uncertainty should the decision be made to go through with not checking up on him. The only difference between this situation and the previous is the framing of the situation.
Key Takeaway: In general, all situations that are based on chance and can have a favorable or unfavorable outcome can be manipulated in largely the same way, by framing favorable or unfavorable, likely and unlikely, and certain and uncertain.
By using metaphors this can be used to persuade people into otherwise risky situations. For instance, most people would prefer the certainty of a paycheck over the uncertainty of owning their own business, but can usually be motivated to reassess that preference when you compare an unknown probabilistic action with one that is well-known and certain, e.g. “Owning a business instead of working for a paycheck is like being taught how to fish instead of being given a fish.”
You can even take the perceived risk-aspect away entirely, which is a trick that salesmen and marketers often use: “We know our product will the best purchase you’ll ever make, but if you aren’t satisfied for any reason within those first 30 days, we’ll give you your money back, guaranteed, no questions asked.”
Or, “If I turn out to be wrong and Rob isn’t lying, I will take full responsibility. I’ll personally apologize and do everything to make things right again between you two. But believe me, Sarah, that guy is cheating on you. I guarantee it.”
Summary
What to use the ambiguity effect for:
To make people reassess their decisions by rewriting their perception of probability, without trying to persuade them openly.
To elicit feelings of doubt by creating ambiguity.
To elicit feelings of certainty by removing ambiguity.
How to defend against the ambiguity effect:
Always make sure that you’re dismissing an option because it’s benefits are unlikely to be worth it, not because you don’t know the exact likelihood that they will be.
Always try to get as much relevant information to weigh into your decisions as possible before making them.
Treat probability fairly, and be wary of those that, intentionally or unintentionally, frame one option more favorable or unfaborable than it realistically is. They might be a key give-away of their own biases and preferences.
Related BetterBytes:
coming soon™
Related Articles:
coming soon™